Are Defined Contributions a New Direction for Employer-Sponsored Coverage?
Issue Brief No. 32
October 2000
Sally Trude, Paul B. Ginsburg
Issue Brief 32
efined contributions for health benefits are being promoted as the new silver bullet
for employers to combat the rising costs of health care, the managed care backlash
and the changing climate for employer liability. As interest in this concept grows,
so does the number of proposed alternatives for implementing it. Originally called
fixed contributions, defined contributions now also refer to cash transfers or vouchers,
with reliance on the individual market for health insurance. A more recent angle for
defined contributions is using the Internet as an on-line marketplace for purchasing
health insurance. This Issue Brief examines defined-contribution strategies and
assesses issues relevant to employers, employees and public policy makers.
Why Defined Contributions?
he renewed interest in a defined-contribution approach to
health benefits has been inspired by the changing approach to pension benefits.
For retirement benefis, the employer contributes to employees pension accounts
based on earnings (defined contribution) instead of guaranteeing a level of
payment upon retirement (defined benefit). This increases portability of pensions
for employees who change jobs, and shifts investment risk and responsibility
from the employer to employees.
Given the growing popularity of defined contributions
for pensions, many benefit consultants and employers are devising similar strategies
for health benefits, hoping to expand choice for employees, contain costs and
relieve employers of the administrative burden of managing health benefits.
Despite the growing interest, few employers have adopted defined contributions
for health benefits. With a tight labor market, employers are cautious about
making any changes that employees might perceive as a reduction in benefits.
Also, depending on the approach taken, employers and employees could lose the
benefit of tax subsidies, risk pooling and bargaining clout with insurers.
Back to Top
Fixed-Dollar Contribution
defined contribution for health benefits was first proposed
in the late 1970s by Alain Enthoven as part of managed competition, an approach
for containing costs through greater price-based competition among health plans.
A fixed-dollar contribution toward health benefits was expected to make employees
more cost conscious because they would pay for any additional benefits beyond
the lowest-cost plan. Over time, as premiums rise, the fixed-dollar amount could
be increased to keep up with the cost of the lowest-price plan. Alternatively,
the fixed-dollar amount could be increased by the general inflation rate, so
that increases in premiums that exceed general inflation are borne by the employee.
Since that time, most employers have begun offering managed care
plans, but relatively few adopted a fixed-dollar contribution strategy. According
to The Robert Wood Johnson Foundation Employer Health Insurance Survey, a component
of the Center for Studying Health System Change (HSC) Community Tracking Study,
only 8 percent of employees who are offered health insurance have a choice of
plans with a fixed-dollar contribution (see Figure 1).
Adopting a fixed-contribution approach requires employers to offer
a choice of health plans, which increases the cost and administrative burden
of offering health insurance. Even among those employees who are offered a choice
of health plans, only 19 percent have a fixed-dollar contribution paid toward
their premium (see Figure 2). In contrast, 18 percent
of employees have the entire premium for each plan offered paid by their employer,
while another 37 percent have a fixed percentage of their premium covered.
Employers who pay a substantial share of the premium may be limited
in their ability to set the contribution rate no higher than the premium of
the lowest-price plan. In a tight labor market or with a unionized workforce,
these employers may be reluctant to reduce their benefits. For example, the
fixed-dollar contribution for state employees covered by the California Public
Employees Retirement System (CalPERS), which is subject to collective bargaining,
exceeds the premiums for many of the plan offerings. As a result, CalPERS employees
have several plan offerings available at no cost, with a limited incentive to
pick the lowest-price plan. To avoid this, employers offer a cafeteria plan,
which allows their employees to apply those savings to other benefits, such
as vision or dental.
A fixed-dollar approach increases employers need to limit adverse
selection. For example, employers can design their benefit offerings and choose
plans to avoid having older or sicker workers select one plan while healthy
young families select another, or they can offer a selection of plans that do
not differ substantially in cost or quality. If adverse selection does occur,
employers can readjust their choice of plans or benefit offerings or risk adjust
payments, paying plans different amounts for different categories of employees.
Health plans also seek to minimize adverse selection through their premiums
and product design and by limiting some employers to a single carrier.
Finally, under a fixed-dollar approach, employers must provide
adequate information for employees to compare the quality of health plans so
they can choose one based on value, not just on cost. This can be expensive
and especially difficult for some employers. National companies must collect
information across many markets, while smaller companies may not have the staff
resources.
Figure 1
Percent of Employees by Contribution Policy of Companies
Offering Insurance
Source: 1997 RWJF Employer Health Insurance Survey
Figure 2
Percent of Employees by Contribution Policy of Companies
Offering a Choice of Plans
Source: 1997 RWJF Employer Health Insurance Survey
Back to Top
Cash Transfers or Vouchers
ecently, defined contributions have been proposed as a way
for employers to step out of the role of health purchaser. Emulating defined
contributions for pension benefits, proponents recommend transferring the risk
and responsibility for health benefits to the employee. To do so, employers
would pay their employees higher wages, and employees could purchase their health
insurance in the individual market. Employers would eliminate the costs and
hassles involved in managing health benefits, and remove themselves from the
firing line of employees grievances with health plans. Xerox sparked some controversy
last year when it discussed such a strategy.
Some critics suggest that this cash approach is tantamount to not offering
insurance. Both employers and employees would lose the tax advantage of having
the employers contribution to the health insurance premium excluded from taxable
income. The Congressional Budget Office estimates that this tax subsidy is roughly
26 percent of health insurance premiums, on average, although the amount of
the tax subsidy varies by income.
Others have proposed vouchers, which would ensure that funds are used for health
insurance and would preserve the tax advantage. Vouchers also allow employers
to transfer funds directly as payroll deductions, avoiding the largeadministrative
costs of collecting regular payments from individuals.
The Employee Benefit Research Institute estimates that premiums to purchase
comparable insurance on the individual market would cost 32 percent more for
employees in companies with more than 1,000 workers, and 24 percent more in
medium-size companies.1 Given the tight labor
market, employers adopting cash transfers or vouchers would have to pay a large
offset to compensate for any loss of the tax subsidy and the higher costs of
health insurance in the individual market.
If employers adopt cash transfers or vouchers, this could end the pooling through
which lower-risk employees subsidize higher-risk employees. Currently, most
employees pay the same amount, regardless of their age and sex, and pay a differential
only to cover their spouse and children. As a result, employees are rarely aware
of payment differentials that account for the higher costs of the older worker
compared to the younger worker. For example, in the individual health insurance
market the premium for the same health plan product may be twice as expensive
for a 50-year-old male as for a 25-year-old male. Nor are employees typically
aware that those with individual coverage subsidize those with family coverage.
Employers may also find that employees resist cash transfers and vouchers because
they do not want to lose the employers ability to advocate on their behalf.
For example, in addition to negotiating premiums, employers play an important
role in resolving poor customer service and employee grievances.
A recent study of employees in large firms found that the workers did not want
to purchase insurance on the individual market because they valued their employers
role in negotiating with insurers over rates and benefits, and in reducing the
complexity of their choices.2 Employees who had had serious illnesses also
valued their employers advocacy role in helping them get the full range of
covered services. A 1999 national survey found that, given current tax laws,
75 percent of employees preferred to get health insurance through their employer
than to receive higher wages and purchase health insurance on their own.3
Back to Top
Internet Innovations
nternet-based ventures are poised to offer technological
strategies to more easily allow employers to implement defined-benefit approaches.
Firms such as eBenX.com and Sageo.com help employers administer their health
benefits and allow employees to choose their health plan on-line. In particular,
these firms can provide performance and provider network information customized
to the employee. For example, some employees may select plans based on customer
service and satisfaction ratings, while others may select plans based on the
availability of a particular physician.
Other Internet ventures may facilitate employers move to defined-contribution
approaches by establishing mechanisms that preserve risk pooling and tax advantages.
The strategies of companies such as HealthSync and Vivius that seek to fill
this niche vary substantially, however. One seeks to establish an on-line marketplace
for choosing health plans, while the other would have consumers customize their
own network of providers and create their own plan. It is still too early to
tell whether these ventures will be successful or what new issues will arise.
Back to Top
Policy Implications
f employers implement defined contributions, public policy
makers will be particularly interested in assessing the potential effect on
the number of uninsured persons. Cash transfers or vouchers could increase the
number of uninsured persons if employer contributions do not cover the higher
costs of insurance adequately in the individual market. Currently, 5 percent
of workers with access to employer-sponsored coverage do not enroll and are
uninsured as a result, principally because of costs. Low-wage workers are much
more likely to be uninsured because of not enrolling in plans they are eligible
for.4
With reliance on the individual market, some older workers or those with chronic
illnesses may find that they cannot obtain or afford coverage. In addition,
cash transfers may increase the number of uninsured young, healthy workers who
might prefer to use their higher wages for other purposes.
On the other hand, some defined-contribution strategies may reduce the number
of uninsured persons by enhancing low-wage workers ability to afford insurance.
For example, an employer may currently cover 75 percent of a health plan with
high premiums. By moving to a fixed-dollar contribution, the employer may cover
the full premium of a lower-priced plan, but have employees pay more for the
higher-priced plan. In this case, more low-wage workers would be likely to take
up insurance. However, this lower-priced plan may have more restrictions, reduced
benefits or higher deductibles. Also, employers efforts to minimize adverse
selection through benefit design and plan selection could limit their ability
to substantially reduce the employee contribution.
Some proposed reforms to improve insurance coverage for small businesses and
self-employed workers could inadvertently encourage some large employers to
adopt defined-contribution approaches. For example, current proposals to make
tax deductions equitable for the self-employed or employees of small businesses
would allow 100 percent tax deductions for health insurance purchased on the
individual market. If the provision does not exclude employees of large companies,
some large employers might be more likely to pursue the cash-transfer approach
to defined contributions.
Finally, employers currently play an important role as advocates on behalf
of their employees-for example, resolving customer service issues and disputes
over coverage. Some employers also play an important role in improving the health
system in general by pushing for patient safety, quality improvement and accountability.
Ironically, although some employers may move toward defined contributions to
sidestep the managed care backlash, erosion of employer-based coverage may intensify
employees concerns. Therefore, a trend toward defined contributions could be
accompanied by additional regulation of health plans through patient protection
legislation.
Back to Top
Defined Contributions: How Relevant Is the Pension Approach
to Health Benefits?
efined contributions for pensions are attractive to employers because they
make retirement savings more portable for people who change jobs and shift responsibility
for investment decisions from employers to employees. These features apply to
health benefits as well, but two key issues do not have a parallel in the pension
world.
One difference with health benefits is the importance of risk pools, where
all employees pay the same amount for coverage, despite large differences in
likely use of services. Some defined-contribution approaches would end this
practice, resulting in substantial redistribution among employees and changing
the population for whom insurance is affordable.
A second difference is risk selection. Because individuals who are more likely
to use services are also more likely to obtain insurance and choose plans with
more extensive benefits, employers and health plans limit the range of choices
to avoid this adverse selection. While the defined-contribution approach to
health benefits arose partly as an attempt to expand choice, the failure of
insurance markets to cope with risk selection remains problematic.
Back to Top
Notes
1. Fronstin, Paul, Presentation to Healthcare Business Media, Inc., Employee
Benefit Research Institute (May 2000). Note: Medium-sized companies have 100
to 999 employees.
2. Lave, Judith, R., et al., "Changing the Employer-Sponsored Health Plan
System: The Views of Employees in Large Firms," Health Affairs, Vol.
18, No. 4 (July/August 1999).
3. Fronstin, Paul, "Employment-Based Health Insurance Remains Popular," Employee
Benefit Research Institute News Brief (April 29, 1999).
4. Cunningham, Peter J., Elizabeth Schaefer and Christopher Hogan, "Who Declines
Employer-Sponsored Health Insurance and Is Uninsured?" Issue Brief No.
22 (October 1999).
Back to Top
ISSUE BRIEFS are published by Health System Change.
President: Paul B. Ginsburg
Director of Public Affairs: Ann C. Greiner
Editor: The Stein Group
|